Tuesday, June 4, 2019
Reducing UK Deficit through Hyperinflation
Reducing UK Deficit through HyperinflationThe unprecedented UK reckon shortf e precise last(predicate)s set out drawn adequate attention to the foreshorten of the ability of the presidency to finance these deficits continuously by adoption ever-increasing quantitys from domestic and foreign residents by take government bonds. What might be particularly lamentable is that, since the 1980s, the UK government has been issuing debt (borrowing) in the current time period to pay back the principal and following due on the debt it issued in previous periods. In other words, it has been simply rolling over increasingly large chunks of government bonds. Adding to this concern is the belief intrinsic to most individuals that there is just aboutthing inherently wrong with deficits and that, eventu exclusivelyy, they would fork up to be centerd to zero.IntroductionBalancing the reckon is equal going to heaven everybody wants to labyrinthine sense the budget, alone nobody wants to do what you fuddle to do to balance the budget Senator Phil Gramm (R Tex.), 1990.Throughout the ages, national economies have get wordd repeated fluctuations about trend in output, employment, prices, and bear on gaits, k without delayn as business cycles. M whatsoever explanations have been offered for these fluctuations in economical activity. They range from sudden supply-side disturbances, or shocks, caused by changes in technology or adverse weather conditions, to unanticipated changes in the bullion supply. too soon business cycle theories assumed that the fluctuations in output and prices about trend were caused by the internal dynamics of a recognizeet economy. Sustained economic enlarge was thought to place severe strains upon the economy. For example, after a prolonged economic recovery, the continually increasing aggregate demand might cause wages and infix costs to rise faster than selling prices. This, according to the archeozoic theories, would pass by to a cutback in business enthronisation and employment as firms, particularly those that had overinvested earlier, started to experience shrinking profits. This link between real and nominal variables, coming in the wake of a sustained period of recovery, was thought to cause recessions.During the era of the lucky standard and fixed veer rates, it was widely believed that business cycles were transmitted across national boundaries by detrimental financial and financial policies of countries that were trading partners. Most of the early theories were in the gold standard era, and hence financial occurrenceors such as bank panics, shortages of liquidity, and fluctuations in relate rates were thought to be primarily answerable for economic downturns.While economists ar by no way unanimous in their analyses of business cycles, the trend today is towards a demand-side money-induced explanation of these cycles in economic activity (Lucas, pp. 7-8).Since 1980s in United Kingdom t here has been a growing feeling amongst economists and indemnity makers that an increase in taxes in the proximo is inevitable. skittishness about the large bond-financed deficits compounded by doomsday predictions in the media has convinced workers that the tax cuts argon temporary. This has stunted the outward shift of restriction supply and labor demand. It remains to be wait onn if the constitute administration does keep taxes at the low levels of 1987 and 1988, or conveniently ignores election year promises and raises them.In this world of individuals with rational expectations, the results of the policies of any one administration ar strongly contingent on the expectations of individuals regarding the continuation of these policies by succeeding administrations. Once again, we must remember that policy is not a one-shot deal, just now a rule or a sequence extending into the contiguous and the past.Economists tend to judgment the aggregate effects of fiscal policy fro m one of troika perspectives. To sharpen the distinctions among them, it is helpful to consider a deficit induced by a lump-sum tax cut today followed by a lump-sum tax increase in the future, holding the path of government purchases and marginal tax rates constant. beneath the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis proposed by Barro, such a deficit volition be fully offset by an increase in close sparing, as taxpayers recognize that the tax is merely postponed, not erectceled. The offsetting increase in private saving means that the deficit forget have no effect on national saving, interest rates, exchange rates, future domestic production, or future national income. A second model, the small open economy view, suggests that budget deficits do reduce national saving but, at the same time, induce increase capital inflows from abroad that finance the entire reduction. As a result, domestic production does not decline and interest rates do not rise, but future national income falls b ecause of the added burden of servicing the increased foreign debt. A third model, which we call the conventional view, likewise holds that deficits reduce national saving but that this reduction is at least partly reflected in lower domestic investment. In this model, budget deficits partly crowd out private investment and partly increase borrowing from abroad the combined effect reduces future national income and future domestic production. The reduction in domestic investment in this model is brought about by an increase in interest rates, thus establishing a connection between deficits and interest rates.Budget deficits argon financed by issuing government bonds to domestic and foreign residents (borrowing) or by selling bonds to the centimeral bank (monetizing the debt). The processes of government spending, taxes, and money creation argon linked quite explicitly by the arithmetic of the intertemporal budget constraint.The most important sources of tax gross for the government argon income taxes, corporate taxes, and payroll taxes. As all these tax revenues are functions of the national income, they consequently decrease when GNP falls, or when the economy goes into recession. On the other hand, direct payments such as unemployment benefits increase in recessions, thereby causing budget deficits to rise in periods of economic sluggishness, even in the absence of any change in fiscal policy. Because of this independence of the magnitude of the deficit to changes in policy, many economists feel that less attention should be paid to the actual deficit and more to what is known as the towering-employment or the standardized-employment deficit (also full-employment deficit, structural deficit). This is a hypothetical construct that replaces both the actual government spending and tax revenues in the actual budget by estimates of what government spending and tax revenues would be, granted up current tax rates and spending provisions, if the economy were op erating at full employment. A 6 per cent unemployment rate is assumed to be the full-employment mark in the UK.The high-employment deficit, therefore, is unaffected by the state of the economy, since it ignores the actual ingestions and tax revenues and instead focuses on what they would be at full employment. This measure of deficit changes save when special(prenominal) policies change, and for this reason economists believe that it is a better indicator of fiscal policy than the actual deficit, as the aggregate business cycle effects have now been sifted out (Baumol and Blinder, pp. 288-290).The inflation-adjusted deficit is the actual deficit adjusted for the inflation component of the interest payments. When the UK government (or any borrower for that matter) pays interest on the government bonds outstanding in an inflationary environment, more dollars must be returned to the lender in recognition of the fact that inflation has eroded the purchasing power of the currency. The se interest payments, made to set up the lenders purchasing power, exaggerate interest expenses and distort the government expenditure figures. To sift out this additional government expenditure due to inflation, we subtract the inflation agio from the interest paid on the national debt, thereby counting only the real interest payments, a technique which provides us with a more sinless measure of the deficits.Large budget deficits financed by money creation are widely believed to be the primary force sustaining prolonged high inflation processes. The race appears to be closer for hyperinflationary episodes, which are usually associated with the presence of massive budget deficits. Hyperinflation, understood in this melodic theme as a process of accelerating inflation, in fact occurs because governments have unsustainably large budget deficits. financial adjustment is a prerequisite for stopping hyperinflation. Suppose the economy is initially at a point like H, moving along the uncertain path with accelerating inflation. The objective of the government is to move the economy to a stable stationary equilibrium such as A. This get out contain a reduction in the deficit to d.sub.0. However, this will not suffice to restore inflation stability since real money balances are under the steady state level (i.e., to the left of A) expansionary pecuniary policy is also needed. This can be achieved through an open market purchase of government bonds. Under rational expectations, the proper combination of fiscal and monetary policies will instantaneously stop hyperinflation (Grossman and Helpman, 1991).In this specific example, as proposed in Dornbusch (1986), expansionary monetary policy set ups the fiscal effort. Indeed, an open market purchase of government bonds reduces the interest payments and the value of the total deficit. The government can thus take advantage of the higher demand for money to reduce the deficit. In this case, the reduction in the prim ary deficit would be smaller than would otherwise need to be. The once-and-for-all increase in the demand for money that results from a successful stabilization effort contributes to a constant reduction in the deficit.The stabilization strategy just discussed is useful to explain the analytical implications of assuming partial tone adjustment in the money market and rational expectations vis--vis instantaneous adjustment in the money market and adaptive expectations. The reduced-form dynamic equations are similar in both cases. However, as just shown, when the right policy combination is followed, hyperinflation can be controlled instantaneously in the former case, while it will at ruff be reduced through a gradual process in the latter. The rigidity in expectations creates a strong barrier to rapid reductions in inflation. there are useful insights regarding the role of tight fiscal policy in anti-inflation programs. First, it is apparent that small reductions in the deficit may not be sufficient to reduce permanently the rate of inflation. Second, it was also argued that there is not a one-to-one relation between deficits and inflation rates while a given budget deficit might be associated with a stable rate of inflation under one set of initial conditions, it could also lead to an unsteady path of prices under others. Finally, there is an interesting asymmetry emerging from this model. While small increases in the budget deficit can move the economy into unstable paths that can eventually result in large increases in inflation, stabilization of the rate of inflation (once the economy is moving along the unstable path) can require even larger contractions in the fiscal deficit. In particular, if the economy is in a sufficiently hyperinflationary state, the monetary authorities might watch that the only practicable stabilizing alternative is the complete elimination of the use of inflationary finance.In this paper it is shown that under plausible assump tions regarding the adjustment of the money market it is possible to find conditions under which large money-financed deficits can lead to hyperinflation even when agents have unadulterated hypermetropy. The basic analytical framework is similar to the one used in Sargent and Wallace (1973), Evans and milfoil (1981), Bruno and Fischer (1986), Dornbusch and Fischer (1986), and Buiter (1987). It assumes that budget deficits are entirely financed through seigniorage, a Cagan-type demand for money function and rational expectations (which in the present model, given the absence of uncertainty, is equivalent to perfect foresight). The main difference is that in the present model the money market does not clear instantaneously.Literature reviewThe adjusted deficit values, therefore, assist us in putting the deficits in perspective and enable us to attribute changes in deficits to specific policy regimes. Another important form of measurement of the budget deficit is the primary deficit . The total budget deficit can be divided into two components the primary or non-interest deficit, and the interest payments on the public debt, that is wide-cut deficit = primary deficit + interest paymentsThe primary deficit therefore represents all government outlays, except interest payments, less all government revenue. This interpretation will have huge significance when we discuss the role of the interest payments on outstanding government bonds. The overall budget might be in deficit even if the primary deficit is in redundancy (or when we have a primary surplus). This is because in every time period the government makes a significant amount of interest payments on past debt. After mandatory spending, interest payments constitute the second largest chunk of UK government expenditures. Thus we can see that the overall budget will be in deficit unless the interest payments on the existing debt are more than matched by a primary surplus (Dornbusch and Fischer, pp. 581-583). A ccording to Dornbusch and Fischer, this forms the core of the mechanics of deficit financing (p. 597). They write If there is a primary deficit in the budget, then the total budget deficit will keep growing as the debt grows because of the deficit, and interest payments rise because the debt is growing.As in Diamond (1965), a deficit is created by the government once and for all increasing its debt by reducing taxes on personal incomes. This is equivalent to the government transferring new bonds to the households. The traditional assumption has been that in subsequent periods taxes on personal incomes are raised in order to pay the interest on this additional debt. Instead, in the present paper I consider the case in which it is the future taxes on bow windows that are raised.In the present model we find that, because taxes on personal incomes are discounted at a higher rate than the interest on government debt, deficits financed by raising future taxes on personal incomes increase wealth and aggregate expenditure, causing a current account deficit. This is the habitual view about the effects of deficits in delimited skyline models.We, however, find that unanticipated deficits financed by raising future taxes on corporate incomes are neutral. This result arises because corporations, unalike households, are infinitely lived, and therefore taxes on corporations are discounted at the same rate as the interest on government debt. Thus, when the government incurs a deficit by transferring new bonds to the households, and it announces that it is going to raise taxes on corporations to pay the interest on these new bonds, the value of shares in corporations falls by the same amount as the value of new bonds that are issued, leaving wealth and aggregate expenditure unchanged.A correction of the fiscal imbalance has been crucial for stopping hyperinflation. This part is well documented in the works of Yeager (1981), Sargent and Wallace (1973), and Webb (1986) on th e hyperinflation episodes in the central European countries and United Kingdom on the episodes of recessions. Substantial reductions in the budget deficit, monetary reform, and a fixed exchange rate were crucial for the successful stabilization policies in those countries. Indeed, fiscal restraint, which in most cases meant outright elimination of the budget deficit, was belike the most important of these policy measures.One distinctive feature of hyperinflationary episodes is that the rate of inflation accelerates over time, thus suggesting that these processes are inherently unstable. Cagans seminal work on this issue provides an alternative interpretation. In Cagans view hyperinflationary episodes could only be unstable if they were self-generating, and he considered that although there is no reason why (self-generating inflations) could not occur so far they have just not been observed (p. 73). However, Cagans stability analysis only considers the case in which the money proces s was exogenous.If one extends Cagans seminal paper through the introduction of money-financed budget deficits and rational expectations, and then analyzes the dynamic properties of the system, as was recently done by Evans and Yarrow (1981), Kiguel (1986), and Buiter (1987), the results are astonishing. Large money-financed budget deficits could be the source of instability however, they could only lead to hyperdeflation. These deficits can never be the source of hyperinflation.The presence of large budget deficits in a perfect foresight framework has a surprising effect on the dynamic behavior of inflation. Auernheimer (1976), Evans and Yarrow (1981), and Kiguel (1986) showed that in order to obtain a hyperinflationary process one demand to assume adaptive expectations. In other words, in Cagans framework, large budget deficits could result in hyperinflation only when agents make systematic mistakes in count oning the rate of inflation.It has been recognized for some time that i t is very difficult to justify the use of adaptive expectations in macroeconomic models. Economic agents eventually learn the process that generates inflation, and they will use that instruction in the formation of their forecasts on inflation. As a result, it is difficult to accept that large budget deficits would lead to accelerating inflation only in the presence of systematic mistakes.The effect of anticipated deficits financed by taxing corporate incomes is the exact opposite of the conventional view about anticipated deficits in finite horizon models. If the government announces that at some future date it will incur a deficit by issuing new bonds to the households, and that corporate income taxes are going to be raised in the periods after that in order to pay the interest on this debt, then at the time the policy is announce aggregate wealth will fall, for the following reason. As taxes on corporations are discounted at the same rate as the interest on government debt, the present value of the taxes is equal to the value of the bonds transferred to the households as of the time that the policy is carried out. However, when the policy is announced households are not sure that they will survive to collect the transfer of bonds. Thus, they discount these transfers at a higher rate than the market rate of interest. On the other hand, as corporations are infinitely lived, the valuation of shares in corporation is such that taxes will be discounted at the market rate of interest. This then means that at the time the policy is announced aggregate wealth and expenditure will fall, causing a current account surplus. This result is the opposite of the conventional view about the effects of anticipated deficits in finite horizon models, as emphasized by, for example, Feldstein (1983), and Frenkel and Razin (1986).Finally, the fact that taxes on corporations in UK are discounted at a lower rate than taxes on personal incomes means that a revenue neutral tax refo rm involving a shift in taxes from personal incomes to corporate incomes will result in a loss of wealth and a fall in aggregate expenditure, causing a current account surplus.Much of the literature on monetary unions has concentrated on their effects on trade and hence on the effects on the efficiency with which factors of production are used. Rose (2000) shows, in a multi-country panel study, that there may be significant effects on trade from membership of a monetary union. Whilst Honahan (2001) does not dispute the potential for benefits, he points out that practically of the weight in Roses results comes from small countries leaving (or sometimes joining) colonial and post-colonial monetary unions. These decisions were practically associated with a bundle of changes in relation to partner countries that themselves had a major impact on trade.Given that there are likely to be reasonably large gains in the scale of trade from joining a monetary union, there are also likely to b e significant increases in the level of output. Grossman and Helpman (1991) argue that there is a strong link between openness and growth and much of the evidence is surveyed in Pain (2002). These gains come from the arrival of new technologies, increases in specialization by comparative advantage and the reaping of economies of scale within industries that have bend more specialized. In addition, a monetary union reduces the barriers to trade even within a common customs area by reducing minutes costs, and this is likely to have a major impact on the level of output that can be produced with a given level of inputs.Given the divinatory importance of the output gap, it is unfortunate that its measurement is so problematic. This will always be the case however when we are trying to separate out high frequency events such as the business cycle from low frequency events or persistent phenomena such as the trend in potential output. As Watson (1986) points out, a time series of 30 ye ars could contain a significant number of examples of cycles of periods of less than 5 years, yet only a hardly a(prenominal) examples of cycles of 10 years or more. Therefore we have more information in a finite sample on the shorter cycles, and correspondingly less information on longer cycles and the permanent shocks (which can be regarded as infinitely long cycles). Techniques for trend inception have to address this problem directly, and filters for trend extraction are designed to remove specific frequencies and, in particular, cycles from the data under consideration.The central point of Feldstein (1986) article is to present empirical evidence in halt of the view that budget deficits cause a currency to appreciate. He regresses the real exchange rate between the U.S. and UK on a measure of the budget deficit in the United Kingdom and a set of other variables. For the period 1973 to 1984 (twelve annual observations), he finds that the estimated effects on the real exchange rate are strong and robust to the inclusion or exclusion of other variables. Branson and Love (1988), on the other hand, outline a theory that assumes that the movements in the nominal exchange rate cause movements in the real exchange rate. These, in turn, cause movements in the supply of (tradable and non-tradable) output and employment and, hence, the trade balance. Their empirical results indicate that custody of dollar over the period caused a large unemployment loss in manufacturing.Barth et al. (1990) note that the choice for measuring of the deficit affects the nature of the linkage between deficits and interest rates. Specifically, studies that use cyclically adjusted deficits or federal debt instead of federal deficits are more likely to find a significant relation between the fiscal variable and interest rates. Recent evidence reported by Barth et al. conforms with these observations.Barth et al. (1990) also conclude that low frequency data (annual versus quarterly or m onthly) and long-term interest rates (instead of short-term rates) are more likely to produce a significant relation between deficits and interest rates. However, recent studies do not support these generalizations. The summary shows that many studies that use quarterly data yield a significant relation between deficits and interest rates (e.g., Bruno and Fischer, 1986 Dornbusch and Fischer, 1986 Buiter, 1987). Moreover, several of the studies surveyed (e.g., Honahan, 2001 Rose, 2000) find a significant relation for short-term interest rates.Barth et al. (1990) note that expected deficits play a greater role than contemporaneous deficits for long-term rates. One should note that results of all such studies are sensitive to the measurement of expected deficits. Frenkel and Razin (1986) find that announcement effects of the unanticipated deficit on interest rates are affirmatory and about the same throughout the yield curve. Both rational expectations studies (Bruno and Fischer, 1986 Dornbusch, 1986) find coercive relations, one for long-term rates and one for short-term. Finally, Feldstein (1983) and Dornbusch and Fischer (1986) find a positive relation between 10-year rates and projected cyclically adjusted deficit as a percent of GNP. Therefore, this relation apparently does exist for long-term rates, but net the same for short-term rates would be premature.DiscussionThe politics of tax cuts are not necessarily straightforward. Since the UK Budget of March 1993, discretionary tax increases have added about pounds 18 billion to expected tax revenue in 1996/97. It might therefore appear odd to the electorate for there to be a absolution of pounds 5 billion of these tax revenues as an election approaches. However, a reasonable defense of this might be that the fiscal position has turned out to be better than originally forecast. When the first tranche of tax increases was announced in the March 1993 Budget it was expected that even with the additional revenu e the PSBR to GDP ratio in 1996/97 would be 4 1/2 per cent of GDP. The additional fiscal changes announced in the November 1993 Budget contributed to a reduction in the forecast deficit to 2 3/4 per cent of GDP. Now, with no further tax changes the Treasury is forecasting that the deficit will be 2 per cent of GDP, substantially lower than they first thought it would be.In terms of the economics of the UK Budget judgment, the slowdown in economic activity that appears to be occurring, peculiarly the very weak state of domestic demand would appear to allow some relaxation of the fiscal stance. In addition, our projections suggest that even after allowing for tax cuts the general government financial deficit will fall below the 3 per cent reference level for the European Union excessive deficits procedure. The main worry with the tax cuts is that they retard the progress that the government has made in reducing its borrowing towards the level that would be permitted by the so-called gold rule that the government borrow no more than is necessary to finance investment. This may be seen either in balance sheet terms or by examining borrowing in relation to investment expenditure.The consequence of the deterioration in the public sectors balance sheet is that this years taxpayers are leaving more liabilities and fewer assets to next years taxpayers than they started with. This suggests that the future services provided by public sector capital will be lower and debt interest higher than they would otherwise have been. This means that future taxes need to be higher in order to pay for the extra debt interest. This situation can be prevented by the government following the golden rule that borrowing be no more than is necessary to finance capital investment.Deficits have to be financed either by issuing debt or by creating base money. Sargent and Wallace (1973) have argued that persistent budget deficits will eventually result either in monetization of the outstand ing stock of debt, thus depriving the monetary authorities of their autonomy in setting policy targets, or in a repudiation of at least part of the debt. Hence lack of fiscal mark off could undermine the independence of a newly created European Central Bank, which might come under potential pressure to loosen its policy stance if some member states had serious budgetary problems. Its credibility could be affected if agents thought that a softer stance would become inevitable to alleviate the financial difficulties of highly obligated(predicate) countries running large deficits. One of the consequences would be an increase in interest rates reflecting a revision in expectations incorporating higher future inflation rates.Fiscal discipline would still be a major concern even if the UK monetary authorities remained steadfast in their anti-inflationary commitment, because those states with unsustainable fiscal positions might have to line out, whose irreversibility would then be ques tioned. As a result, markets could take a different view of the degree of substitutability of the assets issued by the different countries. Furthermore, other externalities would be at work, in the form of pressure on other member states to come to the rescue of those with unsustainable debt/deficit paths. Another possibility is that conflicts would arise on issues related to the dispersion of (seigniorage) among member countries (Pain, 2002). Other consequences for the country as a whole of the lack of fiscal discipline would be a general rise in interest rates and an external deficit for Europe vis--vis the rest of the world, with adverse effects on the ECU exchange rate. As to the introduction of binding fiscal constraints, the argument is often put forward in the literature that they may appear to improve welfare, but only if the existence of a trade-off between fiscal and monetary policy is ignored (Pain, 2002).Development of a government bond market provides a number of impo rtant benefits if the prerequisites to a sound development are in place. At the macroeconomic policy level, the UK government securities market provides an avenue for domestic funding of budget deficits other than that provided by the central bank and, thereby, can reduce the need for direct and potentially damaging monetary financing of government deficits and avoid a build-up of foreign currency denominated debt. A government securities market can also strengthen the transmission and implementation of monetary policy, including the achievement of monetary targets or inflation objectives, and can enable the use of market-based indirect monetary policy instruments. The existence of such a market not only can enable authorities to smooth consumption and investment expenditures in response to shocks, but if coupled with sound debt management, can also help governments reduce their exposure to interest rate, currency, and other financial risks. Finally, a shift toward market-oriented funding of government budget deficits will reduce debt-service costs over the medium to long term through development of a deep and liquid market for government securities. At the microeconomic level, development of a domestic securities market can increase overall financial stability and improve financial intermediation through greater competition and development of related financial infrastructure, products, and services.The creation of a monetary union will inevitably affect the setting of fiscal policy. Even if only monetary policy becomes the responsibility of the new institutions, with fiscal policy remaining in the domain of national government, the fact that they will no longer be able to monetize debt has implications for policy choices. Fiscal policy may play a more important role as a stabilization tool. In the standard Mundell-Fleming framework, in which sticky prices are assumed (Frankel and Razin, 1987) fiscal policy is most effective when exchange rates are fixed and there are free capital movements, conditions which has to be fulfilled by the UK government. Because in a fixed rate system a fiscal expansion does not lead to a rise in interest rates and to an appreciation of the exchange rate, some countries might resort more frequently to fiscal measures to respond to shocks, especially if they are country-specific. Such budgetary policies could result in a looser overall fiscal stance, especially if the fiscal authorities failed to distinguish between temporary and permanent shocks. It is often claimed that fiscal policy is the appropriate policy resp
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.